20 April, 2024

Blog

Central Bank’s Profits/Losses Have No Relevance For Its Conduct Of Monetary Policy

By Sirimevan Colombage

Prof. Sirimevan Colombage

Prof. Sirimevan Colombage

Several newspaper articles have appeared recently with regard to the losses incurred by the Central Bank for the third consecutive year in 2015. A critic has alleged that the continuously loss-making Central Bank is no better than SriLankan Airlines. It was further argued that when a central bank becomes bankrupt with a negative networth due to continued losses, the public as the owners of the central bank are required to recapitalize the bank at great costs.

A clarification on these issues is called for as such haphazard remarks might give a wrong impression to the public that the Central Bank is just another inefficient loss-making public enterprise that needs to be recapitalized using public funds to avoid bankruptcy.

In the context of the broader national economic goals assigned to the Central Bank as the country’s monetary authority, it is inaccurate to equalize the Bank with a loss-making airline which became bankrupt due to its own mismanagement. The implications of profits or losses of a central bank need to be analyzed by taking into account its unparalleled legal status in the monetary system rather than partially looking at a decline in its capital base as in the case of a commercial entity.

Central banks are not commercial enterprises

Central banks all over the world have been functioning as public policy institutions but not as commercial ventures which are driven by the profit maximization motive.

In terms of the Monetary Law Act (MLA), the objectives of the Central Bank of Sri Lanka are to ensure (a) economic and price stability, and (b) financial system stability, with a view to encouraging and promoting the development of the productive resources.

Hence, one could argue that it is inappropriate to equate the Central Bank with a commercial enterprise like a loss-making airline, and to conclude that the Bank would go bankrupt with its continuous losses. Admittedly, empirical evidence suggests that a stronger capital base of a central bank helps to carry out its functions smoothly without compromising its independence. But it does not mean that central banks should drive their monetary policy operations keeping profit motive in the forefront undermining its monetary policy objectives which are of broader national interest.

Central banking beyond profits/losses

While recognizing the point that a stronger capital base enables a central bank to act more independently without resorting to government funds, a different line of argument that one could put forward is that the core objective of the central banks is to achieve price stability through monetary policy operations but not to make profits.

In analyzing the effectiveness of a central bank, therefore, due recognition must be given to its monetary policy operations going beyond its profits/losses in a pure accounting sense. A profit-making central bank is not necessarily better than a loss-making one, as the success of both institutions depends on the way in which monetary policy is conducted by each of them, but not by the levels of their profits or losses per se.

The monetary policy adopted by the Central Banka since 2012 until about mid-2015 had adverse effects on the Sri Lankan economy. It had reduced the policy (interest) rates continuously while defending the rupee at an overvalued exchange rate during that period. Such policy stance had led to create excess liquidity in the market overheating the economy with resultant demand pressures as reflected in the continuous rise in imports and core inflation even now.

It is only during the recent months that the Central Bank has allowed greater flexibility in the exchange rate and interest rates so as to respond to market realities. Accordingly, the ongoing depreciation of the exchange rate and the rise in market interest rates would help to rectify macroeconomic fundamentals which had been in disarray for a long time.

Cost of monetary operations inevitable

A central bank’s profit/loss is a by-product of its monetary policy actions encompassing policy rates, open market operations, statutory reserve ratio, exchange rate and foreign currency investments. The bank’s decisions on such operations are governed by the prevailing monetary policy stance rather than by any profit maximization motive, as mentioned earlier. Inevitably, monetary policy operations may result in losses at times.

The losses incurred by the Central Bank increased from Rs. 24 billion in 2013 to Rs. 32 billion in 2014, and declined to Rs. 20 billion in 2015 reflecting an improvement in its finances. A closer analysis of the accounts reveals that the recent losses of the Central Banka was almost entirely an outcome of revaluation of its foreign reserves due to currency fluctuations.

Certain favourable effects of a prudent monetary policy such as a stable financial system or a low inflation environment are beneficial from the societal point of view, but the internal financial effects of such underlying policy measures may ultimately get recorded as losses in the accounting statements of the central bank. Therefore, it might be unreasonable to discredit the Central Bank on such grounds without taking into account the wider macroeconomic effects.

No common capital adequacy norms

Being the monetary authority in charge of financial regulation and supervision, a central bank is required to maintain an adequate level of capital enabling it to function independently without resorting to government coffers for recapitalization.

Universally, however, there is no common agreement on the optimal quantity of capital that should be maintained by a central bank. It is broadly accepted that central banks need to maintain risk-based, non-negative level of capital.

As per MLA, the required capital for the Central Bank is Rs. 15 million which may be increased up to a maximum of Rs. 50 billion. Its capital funds now stand at Rs. 50 billion which is the maximum level stipulated in MLA. The total amount of equity, however, declined from Rs. 115 billion in 2013 to Rs. 82 billion in 2014 and to 54 billion in 2015 due to the downward trend in reserves.

A major factor that may have contributed to the decline in reserves is the transfer of Central Bank’s surpluses to the government which is the sole shareholder. Funds were transferred even during the loss making years. Certain legal limits have been imposed on central bank’s profit distribution in some countries to avoid capital depletion.

Central banks cannot go bankrupt easily

When an unprofitable commercial venture like the Sri Lankan Airlines finds it impossible to continue its business due to unsustainable debts, it would be declared bankrupt. This is hardly relevant to a central bank however much it is weak in terms of the conventional accounting standards.

Although set up as banks, the central banks are not subject to company laws, bankruptcy procedures or minimum capital requirements. A central bank could become “balance sheet-insolvent” with its liabilities exceeding assets. Yet, it can continue its operations without any hindrance, as it remains immune to bankruptcy procedures and other related regulations.

“Bankruptcy” is a legal status of an entity that cannot repay the debts it owes to creditors. So, an immediate question to be raised is, what debts does the Central Bank “owe”. Currency in circulation, deposits of commercial banks, other financial institutions and government are the major liabilities of the central bank.

The central bank is in an exclusive position having its biggest component of liabilities in the form of currency as the legal tender of the country issued by the bank itself. Hence, it is said as long as the notes and coins issued by a central bank are acceptable to the public as legal tender, it can never go bankrupt! However, there are a few exceptions that central banks fail to function under extreme conditions. The Central Bank of the Philippines which was declared bankrupt in 1993 is such a rare case.

The comprehensive networth of a central bank is greater than the net assets registered in its published balance sheet. The reason is that the published balance sheets do not capture intangible assets such as the franchise value of the monopoly right of the central bank to issue base money.

Whenever creditors decide to withdraw their deposits from the central bank in large scales, it can meet such demand by printing new currency at will. However, that does not mean central banks are free to issue unlimited amounts of currency which might lead to accelerate inflation defeating the price stability objective. When the general price level rises rapidly leading to ‘hyper-inflation’, the domestic currency would erode to the extent that it is rejected by the public. That is the limit faced by central banks in issuing new money.

Central Bank’s networth unmoved

The Central Bank being the monetary authority of the country has broader obligations to be fulfilled in the interest of the national economy. When conducting its monetary policy operations focusing on national goals, it may incur unavoidable losses at times. In this context, it is unfair to bring the Central Bank into disrepute on such grounds disregarding the wider macroeconomic effects of its monetary policy operations.

The Bank’s recent losses were almost entirely due to the revaluation of foreign reserves associated with currency fluctuations. Although such losses may adversely affect the financial strength of the Bank in the short run, it has the ability to improve its networth over the long run, given the bank’s prime position as the country’s monetary authority and the sole currency issuer. The implicit limit of currency printing in the extreme is refusal to accept currency by the general public which seems a remote possibility in the case of Sri Lanka at present.

“Seigniorage” or profit earned by the Central Bank by issuing currency is not reflected in its profit/loss account, but interest earnings accrued through the securities exchanged for currency is reflected as profits making it financially sound over time. The Bank’s networth is much larger than what is reflected in its balance sheet as the seigniorage is not captured in typical accounting.

The financial strength of a central bank goes beyond the mere financial resources and includes risk transfer mechanisms such as the rules governing distribution of profits. The Central Bank claims that it has taken positive steps in these directions since 2015.

While recognizing the need to maintain adequate capital so as to meet the potential risks and to safeguard independence, the performance of a central bank should be judged in terms of the effectiveness of its monetary policy operations rather than by partially looking at its profits or losses per se.

*Prof. Sirimevan Colombage, an economist, academic and former central banker, can be reached at sscolom@gmail.com

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

Latest comments

  • 5
    1

    Needleless to say is very full of information and current operation of CB has been revealed by Dr S.Colombage .

    In my view that every body need to be study essence of essay by
    DR Colombage’s writing.

  • 4
    0

    Two very interesting divergent views expressed by two former Central Bankers whether CB should watching the bottom line like the commercial banks. As the CB has a major role to play in directing the economy and ensure price stability by using fiscal and monetary policy measures which may be unpalatable but very necessary in the long run sacrificing the profit motive is justifiable.

  • 2
    1

    But Hema Senanayake says this is all nonsense? Who is Hema Senanayake anyway?

Leave A Comment

Comments should not exceed 200 words. Embedding external links and writing in capital letters are discouraged. Commenting is automatically disabled after 5 days and approval may take up to 24 hours. Please read our Comments Policy for further details. Your email address will not be published.